Customize Consent Preferences

We use cookies to help you navigate efficiently and perform certain functions. You will find detailed information about all cookies under each consent category below.

The cookies that are categorized as "Necessary" are stored on your browser as they are essential for enabling the basic functionalities of the site. ... 

Always Active

Necessary cookies are required to enable the basic features of this site, such as providing secure log-in or adjusting your consent preferences. These cookies do not store any personally identifiable data.

No cookies to display.

Functional cookies help perform certain functionalities like sharing the content of the website on social media platforms, collecting feedback, and other third-party features.

No cookies to display.

Analytical cookies are used to understand how visitors interact with the website. These cookies help provide information on metrics such as the number of visitors, bounce rate, traffic source, etc.

No cookies to display.

Performance cookies are used to understand and analyze the key performance indexes of the website which helps in delivering a better user experience for the visitors.

No cookies to display.

Advertisement cookies are used to provide visitors with customized advertisements based on the pages you visited previously and to analyze the effectiveness of the ad campaigns.

No cookies to display.

Connect with us

Hi, what are you looking for?

slide 3 of 2

Kenneth Arrow: Who he was, Theorem, Legacy

File Photo: Kenneth Arrow: Who he was, Theorem, Legacy
File Photo: Kenneth Arrow: Who he was, Theorem, Legacy File Photo: Kenneth Arrow: Who he was, Theorem, Legacy

Kenneth Arrow Personality?

American neoclassical economist Kenneth Arrow (1921–2017) shared the 1972 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics with John Hicks for their work on welfare economics and general equilibrium analysis.

Along with these and other subjects, Arrow’s research has also examined the economics of racial discrimination, information economics, collective decision-making, social choice theory, and endogenous growth theory.

Being cognizant, Ken Arrow

Kenneth Arrow was a professor at the Universities of Chicago, Harvard, and Stanford after being born in New York City in 1921. The General Impossibility Theory, a theory he developed, was the subject of his dissertation, which helped him receive his doctorate from Columbia University.

This theorem established Arrow’s conclusion that election results could not be decided fairly. He explained this by saying there is no perfect voting process when more than two candidates are vying to meet the exact requirements.

Nondictatorship: The role of a single individual should not be paramount. This suggests that everyone’s desires ought to be taken into account.

Voters should be able to arrange their selections however they see fit under individual sovereignty. Also, if there’s a tie or they’re unsure, they should be allowed to mark it down.

Uniformity: The group ranking should reflect each voter’s preferences over each other.

The absence of one option should not affect the outcomes of the others, as freedom and independence from unnecessary options are paramount. As a result, the front-runner ought to remain ahead of the rear-runner even if the third candidate withdraws.

Be unique in your group rank. The outcome should be the same regardless of personal preferences.

It is not just about democracy and election outcomes that Arrow’s General Impossibility Theorem is applied. It is associated with the liberal paradox, formulated by economist Amartya Sen, and has been used in welfare economics and (social) justice. Sen and his paradox state that because individual freedom and the distribution of goods and services in a society cannot coexist, there is typically a conflict between the two.

Kenneth Arrow’s lasting legacy

Arrow claimed that his conclusions regarding the operation of competitive markets were held only under ideal or unrealistic assumptions. Despite this, his theoretical insight has been demonstrated to be significant over decades. Third-party effects were not likely under these conditions. The idea that Harry selling Joe a product wouldn’t impact Sally’s well-being is one example of this effect. However, the sale of goods that have negative consequences for the environment and other things frequently goes against this principle in the real world.

Subsequent research by Arrow transformed straightforward concepts into sophisticated mathematical expressions, which other economists carried out in unexpected ways. Arrow studied a concept in the early 1960s: “learning by doing.” The gist was that an organization evolved more intelligently the more it produced.

Economists adopted this concept decades later into complex theories of “endogenous growth,” which contend that internal business initiatives that support innovation and learning are the primary drivers of economic growth.

Conclusion

  • Kenneth Arrow was a neoclassical economist who made a lot of significant advances in both microeconomics and macroeconomics.
  • Arrow won the Nobel Prize in 1972 for his welfare economics and general equilibrium work.
  • Arrow’s most important contributions to economic theory are his works on social choice theory, especially his “impossibility theorem.”

You May Also Like

Notice: The Biznob uses cookies to provide necessary website functionality, improve your experience and analyze our traffic. By using our website, you agree to our Privacy Policy and our Cookie Policy.

Ok